Foreign exchange rate expectations: Micro survey data

pdf
Số trang Foreign exchange rate expectations: Micro survey data 45 Cỡ tệp Foreign exchange rate expectations: Micro survey data 426 KB Lượt tải Foreign exchange rate expectations: Micro survey data 0 Lượt đọc Foreign exchange rate expectations: Micro survey data 0
Đánh giá Foreign exchange rate expectations: Micro survey data
5 ( 12 lượt)
Nhấn vào bên dưới để tải tài liệu
Đang xem trước 10 trên tổng 45 trang, để tải xuống xem đầy đủ hãy nhấn vào bên trên
Chủ đề liên quan

Nội dung

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FOREIGN EXCHANGE RATE EXPECTATIONS: MICRO SURVEY DATA Takatoshi Ito Working Paper No. 2679 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 MassachusettsAvenue Cambridge MA 02138 August 1988 Discussions with Jeffrey A. Frankel, Kenneth A. Froot, Hidehiko Ichimura, Maurice Obstfeld, and Chriatoper Sims were very useful. I have benefitted from comments received form participants of seminars at Harvard University, University of Minnesota, University of California at San Diego and National Bureau of Ecunuaic Research. I thank the Japan Center for International Finance, especially President Iomomitsu Ohs and Vice President Shoji Ochi, Financial for having made the survey data in the Tokyo market available. SES-8808828 and from support from National Science Foundation grant number is Japan Economic Research Foundation, [Nihon Keizai Kenkyu Shorei Zaidan] research program in research is of NBER's This part gratefully acknowledged. International Studies. Any opinions expressed are those of the author not those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER Working Paper #2679 August 11988 FOREIGN EXCHANGE RATE EXPECTATIONS: MICRO SURVEY DATA ABSTRACT This conducted paper analyzes the panel data of bi—weekly surveys, by the Japan Center for International Finance, on the of forty—four institutions yen/dollar exchange rate expectations for two years. this There are three major findings in paper. First, market participants are found to be heterogeneous. are significant formation. "individual Second, effects" in expectation many institutions are found to rational expectation hypothesis. Third, horizons showed horizons. their less violate forecasts with yen appreciation than There those Cross-equation constraints implied by the with the long short consistency the data. of the forecast term structure are strongly rejected in Takatoshi Ito Institute of Economic Research 1-Jitotsubashi University Kunitachi, Tokyo, 186 Japan 1. Introduction rational expectations have become a popular benchmark in As financial and interested in Although macroeconomic hypotheses, survey data on many domestic variables, market including participants. interest rates many inflation rates, have been frequently analyzed by and become more many economists have directly measuring expectations of thinkctng investigators for example. Miahkin (1983; ch. 4)). it is only recently that (see, data on foreign exchange rates have become available survey been analyzed. and Dominguez (1986) and Frankel and Froot (1987a.b) have exploited the survey data made available by the Money Market Service (MMS). the Amex Bank Review and the Economist Financial Report.1 The Froot surveys Frankel and Heterogeneity among the and by that were investigated by Dominguez. have only their median responses reported. market participants, if it existed, is aggregated out. If market the with consists of homogeneous agents which share the same forecasting model common belief (priors) and information, then the median sufficiently describe the market in terms of forecasts. response would if However, participants differ in their forecasting characteristics, market focusing on the median misses the most interesting questions such as whehter the differences persist or are temporary, whether the difference is correlated with the participant's traits, and whether a rationality hypothesis is more Likely to be rejected in individual data. Only individual responses of survey data could answer these questions. In this paper, I will use the survey data collected by the Japan Center for International Finance (JCIF) in Tokyo, which allows me the individual responses in the survey.2 In particular the JCIF data has two distinct advantages over other data used by -1- to investigate Dominguem, and set by Frankel with and Froot. the JCIF data consist of First, Second. not only financial no missing observations. other are companies individual responses polled in the JCIF survey. institutions but Therefore, chance to associate possible heterogeneity to forecasters' There are are participants "individual three major found effects" in to in findings be this are There significant Second, many institutions ace found to violate the rational expectation hypothesis. them underestimated the degree of yen appreciation. of with long horizons showed horizons. Put differently, Third, Most forecasts less yen appreciation than ones with short market participants appear to have a "bandwagon" expectation in the short-run, "twist" a market First, expectation formation. their is industry traits. paper. heterogeneous. there but a "stabilizing" one in the long-run. in forecast term structure could be "internally consistent" sense of Froot and Ito (1988)), if an iterated substitution of a forecast yields a long-term forecast, However, The (in the short-term cross-equation constraints implied by the internal consistency are strongly rejected in the data, 2. Data Summary 2.A. The Data Description The JCIF has conducted and - a telephone survey twice a month, in the the end of the month, on Wednesdays, yen/dollar exchange obtained from brokers, 4 rate for and foreign exchange experts in 44 securities companies, Forecasts of since May 1985. one-, three- 6 trading middle the six-month horizons are companies; companies. 9 15 banks and export-oriented companies S life insurance companies, and 5 import-oriented industries,4 The survey It is meticulously arranged so that all 44 companies on the permanent list respond every week, -2- ihen the mean the rndivi- following, mean across forty-four individuals at a time wrll be referred to as an the mean across individuals at a time in an (cross-section. total) average: The mean across time industry group will be referred to as a group average. of an individual, as across :n and the mean across time should not be confused. duals the a data set is analyzed as a panel data, the (time) "average" will be referred of a group, or of the total mean of the individual, of the group. or of the to avetage, respectively. The JCIF calculates minimum the total average, of forty-four responses overall including average and group ICIF informs ita statistics. The those who are polled, of the summary (cross-section) maximum, and also industry group averages and On the day after che survey, the standard deviations. members, standard deviation, is also released to the press and other media. I the will use, in addition to the panel data of forty-four companies, information part of the survey: the cross-section average public different industries: forty-four companies and group averages for securities companies (SEC) (BAN), (AyE) trading companies companies in the export industries (EXP), insurance companies in the import industries (IMP). [Sogo Shosha] dollar, so that negative movement indicates exchange rate, s(t), is measured at the closing quote banks (TRA), companies (INS), The unit is yen per yen "appreciation." in Tokyo on of and one U.S. The spot Wednesday of the survey week. 2.B Overview Let us illustrate the average (aggregate) expectation and the of actual exchange rates during the one-year turbulent Oroup of Five, Plaza Agreement of September 1985. -3- movement period following the In Figure 1, the solid line is the actual daily spot rate, while the base of each sequence of three arrows shows the timing of the poll and the spot exchange rate of that day. Three arrows, of average Therefore, respectively, point to the forecasted exchange rate the forty four) with the one-. thpee- and mistake of FIGURE several by this figure, 1 the ABOUT HERE two preliminary observations emerge. (See Ito (1987) for "news" analyeia of market, rate the expectation. First, each waves of aharp appreciation does not seem to have been these of anticipated appreciation Second, the long-run expectation is not the simple extrapolation of waves,) the six-month horizons. the vertical deviation of the tip of an arrow from the spot (solid) line represents an ex From (the short-run In fact, there seems to expectations. be a in "twist" expectation term structure, order to quantify these observations and to extend observations to In group aggregates and provided. changes Table reaponaea, Table 1 shows that the time means of 1 and Figure (unconditional) are 2 expected (in percent) from the spot rate at the, time of survey for the cross- section total table) individual for average, group averages, and (in each individual. a separate distribution For the purpose of discussion, the mean of forward premium (FOR) and the actual (ex Q9,f) changes of the spot exchange rate (ACT) for each horizon are reported in the same table. For each horizon and each individual or group, subtracting the forward premium from the forecasts yields the implied risk premium and subtracting the changes produces the forecast errors, TABLE 1 and FIGURE -4- 2 about here actual the In one-month horizon, the (total) average expected a 1.4 percent yen appreciation. percent to 2 percent appreciation. on a week typical The group averages ranged from 0.8 In relative to total average, the export industry was most biased toward yen depreciation and trading companies import industries were most biased toward yen appreciation. individual data, one extreme predicted while the other extreme predicted 1.4 percent into Looking depreciation of 3.1 percent of appreciation. The bution of individual forecasts has a nice unimodal distribution. change is at about one-fifth in the distribution, and yen. distri- The actual that is. about 20 of participants overpredicted rhe size of yen appreciation in the percent one-month horizon. The mean of forward premium (FOR) was 0.15 percent. that indicating there was a risk premium for most of the participants in favor of the dollar The mean of actual changes for a one-month period was asset. during the companies two years of the sample period. The forecasts 2.1 percent by trading with 2.0 percent and import companies with 1.9 percent came to the actual movement. close All groups and a majority of individuals did better in forecasting than the forward rate in the one-month horizon. The expected appreciation of the yen in the three-month horizon for the average was that about the same as the one-month 1.4 percent, no adjustment is made with respect to the length of horizon. (Note horizon.) Hence, the aggregate forecasts, one-month and three-month combined, imply that they predict little movement after the first month to the third month in the forecast horizon. However, this statement will be qualified shortly when we examine the individual responses. ciation in three months. The actual change was 6 percent appre- The total and group averages underpredicted the size of yen appreciation by 3 to 5 percentage points. -5- In fact, the most yen appreciation predicted by an individual is 4.3 percent. and no individual overpredicted the size of yen appreciation in the three-month horizon. As in the one-month horizon, bias the (from total appreciation bias average), the export industry has a yen depreciation and the trading in the three-month horizon. have a companies The implied risk that the export industry would have a negative risk premium shows dollar asset, while others have a positive risk premium as in the premium for the one-month This makes sense considering that exporters are long horizon. yen in dollar assets in the medium run. Wide disagreement among individuals starts to show in the It becomes a bi-mod.al distribution: forecasts. yen three-month one group believes that the depreciates from the one-month to three-month in the forecast horizon. while the other believes that the yen continues to appreciate. bution also has long tails. and The distri- Therefore, although the group averages for one- three-monthhorizons predict a yen appreciation of about the same size (1.4 percent). distributions of individual responses are quite different. The last observation illustrates how important it is to have a data set with individual responses rather than one with the summary statistics. For the six-month horizon, the total average practically shows that the market expects forecast. the yen to return to the prevailing level at time of This is a sharp turnaround from the forecast of 1.4 percent appreciation in three months. that the In fact, each of the group averages indicates the group anticipates less yen appreciation in the than either of yen the one- or three-month horizons. six-month horizon The agreement among different groups in forecasting the sharp yen appreciation from the third to the sixth month is quite striking, since they differ -6- in forecasting the direction of the yen from the firsr to the third month. In premium the six-month horizon, all of the groups for the dollar denominated asset. have a negative risk This contrasts to the positive risk premium in the one-month horizon. The distribution of individuals is almost uniform ranging from a percent depreciation to a one percent appreciation. of the individual forecasts. three highlighting a diversity It is clear from the figure that the degree of diversity increases as the forecast horizon is longer. Again looking at the average would not give this observation. Findings of this section can be aummarized and related to the of the rest of this paper. First, the findings are highly heterogeneous market participants. the contents suggestive of A rigorous analysis and interpretation of heterogeneity will be provided in Section 3. Second, large forecast errors were recorded during the intermittent waves of yen appreciation after September 1985. while, the appreciation. whether However, when the exchange rate was relatively stable for a one-month market Therefore, it expectation overpredicted the is not immediately clear from expectations were unbiased. individual) time means without test statistics. the (ACT) shows These observations are the of figures In Table 1, a comparison of group with the actual change forecast errors for each horizon. amount (or average only suggestive Econometric tests on varioua forms of the rational expectation hypothesis will be conducted in Section 4. Third, the short-horizon expectations seem to predict yen appreciation, while the long-horizon expectations seem to predict a reverse in direction. Thus, their the total average and most of the group averages have a forecasts, Section 5 investigates expectations are internally consistent. whether such "twist' in twists in Wishful Expectations and Heterogeneity 3. 3.A. Econometric that Recall our special case of micro survey data and fifty-one observations. individuals formation at individual j, j individual a j: u(t) is the expected exchange given rate for (3.1) a pure spot exchange rate at time t. random disturbance representing. The cross-section average of for individual f(I(t)) + cAVE + uAVE(t) (32) (E s(t))/J, cAVE — (E ej)/.J and uAVE contains a possible. a For the 5XVE(t) is defined as 5XVE(t) f(I(t)) on based J (where in this paper J=44) is 1 measurement error. 5AVE(t) where that an individual forecast f(I(tY and the individual effect. ej. where si(t) is a k-step ahead forecast of the forecasts, forty-four f(I(t)) + ej ÷ uj(t) si(t) example, consists of set Suppose forecast horizon, k (suppressed notation), by data time t consists of the common structural part information, public a -- Issue (E Assume u1)/J. constant term so that normalization, CAVE — 0. is Then subtracting each side of (3.2) from the corresponding side of (3.1), we obtain s(t) The - 5XVE(t) — ej + (uj(t) - uAvE(t)) (3.3) estimator of individual effect. ej can be obtained by regressing the lefthand side of (3.3) on a constant over the sample period (across This procedure is simple and robust. It is unnecessary for econometrician to know the exact structure f(I(t)) as long as it is -8- time). the common
This site is protected by reCAPTCHA and the Google Privacy Policy and Terms of Service apply.